Democracy and human rights are only associated with higher welfare holding income constant in some countries

By Vasco Grilo🔸 @ 2024-10-01T16:06 (+7)

The views expressed here are my own, not those of my employers.

Summary

Introduction

People in more democratic countries tend to live longer, and countries where people live longer tend to have higher life satisfaction. I checked whether similar relationships hold within countries holding real GDP per capita constant.

Methods

I run within-country linear regressions of the population size, life expectancy at birth, share of people who are satisfied with their life, and life satisfaction on the logarithm of the real GDP per capita, and either the Varieties of Democracy’s electoral democracy index or civil liberties index (human rights index). I aggregated results across all countries, and ones in the European Union (EU).

Results

The calculations and full results are in this sheet.

Democracy

World

Within-country linear regressions of the metric below on the Varieties of Democracy's electoral democracy index and logarithm of the real GDP per capitaNumber of entitiesPoints per entityMean derivative with respect to the democracy indexFraction of entities where more democracy is good
Population17255.05.46E+0764.5 %
Life expectancy at birth17255.034.169.8 %
Share of people who are satisfied with their life354.28-1.7137.1 %
Life satisfaction1609.97-1.9045.0 %

EU

Within-country linear regressions of the metric below on the Varieties of Democracy's electoral democracy index and logarithm of the real GDP per capitaNumber of entitiesPoints per entityMean derivative with respect to the democracy indexFraction of entities where more democracy is good
Population2751.2-4.19E+0625.9 %
Life expectancy at birth2751.213.877.8 %
Share of people who are satisfied with their life2724.0-0.42240.7 %
Life satisfaction2711.01.4748.1 %

Human rights

World

Within-country linear regressions of the metric below on the civil liberties index and logarithm of the real GDP per capitaNumber of entitiesPoints per entityMean derivative with respect to the human rights indexFraction of entities where more human rights is good
Population17255.01.56E+0762.2 %
Life expectancy at birth17255.08.5563.4 %

Share of people who are satisfied with their life[1]

3521.1-2.20E+1228.6 %
Life satisfaction1609.97-0.33142.5 %

EU

Within-country linear regressions of the metric below on the civil liberties index and logarithm of the real GDP per capitaNumber of entitiesPoints per entityMean derivative with respect to the human rights indexFraction of entities where more human rights is good
Population2751.2-1.63E+0714.8 %
Life expectancy at birth2751.2-16.955.6 %
Share of people who are satisfied with their life2724.0-2.69E+1229.6 %
Life satisfaction2711.0-2.2733.3 %

Discussion

According to my results, holding real GDP per capita constant, a higher:

These results suggest more democracy and human rights, holding real GDP per capita constant, are associated with a higher welfare in a random country in the world, and a negative one in a random country in the EU[2]. I expect the results to become less favourable to democracy and human rights after controlling for sanctions from and conflicts/cooperation with the West as done in Park 2024, although not much since I already controlled for real GDP per capita. In any case, I think the key takeaways is that there is significant cross-country variation, both globally and in the EU.

  1. ^

     This index only respects countries in Europe.

  2. ^

     Across all countries excluding the regressions on the share of people satisfied with their life, which only respect Europe’s countries, 66.7 % (4 out) of the 6 mentioned mean effects are positive. Across EU’s countries, 25.0 % (2 out) of the 8 mentioned mean effects are positive. In contrast, 100 % (16 out) of the 16 mean effects with respect to the logarithm of the real GDP per capita are positive.


Ben Millwood🔸 @ 2024-10-01T23:35 (+4)

I would guess that some of the welfare benefits of democracy and human rights both flow from and flow to greater economic prosperity, so holding those things constant may suppress some of the "true" effect.

Vasco Grilo🔸 @ 2024-10-02T07:03 (+2)

Thanks for the good point, Ben. I think it is unclear whether democracy and human rights cause economic prosperity. I guess it depends on the context. In addition, democracy may cause economic prosperity due to favours from rich democratic nations instead of the institutional qualities of democracy per se, as argued in Democratic Favor Channel. Here is the abstract (emphasis mine):

A large body of literature in economics and political science examines the impact of democracy and political freedoms on various outcomes using cross-country comparisons. This paper explores the possibility that any positive impact of democracy observed in these studies might be attributed to powerful democratic nations, their allies, and international organizations treating democracies more favorably than nondemocracies, a concept I refer to as democratic favor channel. Firstly, after I control for being targeted by sanctions from G7 or the United Nations and having military confrontations and cooperation with the West, most of the positive effects of democracy on growth in cross-country panel regressions become insignificant or negatively significant. Secondly, using the same empirical specification as this literature for demonstrating intermediating forces, I show that getting sanctioned, militarily attacked, and not having defense cooperation with the West are plausible channels through which democracy causes growth. Lastly, in the pre-Soviet-collapse period, which coincides with the time when democracy promotion was less often used as a justification for sanctions, the impact of democracy on GDP per capita is already weak or negative without any additional controls, and it becomes further negative once democratic favor is controlled. These findings support the democratic favor channel and challenge the idea that the institutional qualities of democracy per se lead to desirable outcomes. The critique provided in this paper applies to the broader comparative institutions literature in social sciences and political philosophy.