Shallow Report on Productivity

By Joel TanπŸ”Έ @ 2023-01-25T08:18 (+24)

Note: This report was produced with only one week of desktop research, for the purpose of identifying promising causes to evaluate at depth. We only have low confidence in our findings here, and the conclusions should generally be taken by readers as merely suggestive rather determinative.


Summary

Factoring in the expected benefits of higher economic productivity (i.e. greater economic output and also improved health), as well as the tractability of educational streaming advocacy, I find that the marginal expected value of educational streaming advocacy to boost productivity to be 5,582 DALYs per USD 100,000, which is around 9x as cost-effective as giving to a GiveWell top charity (CEA).

Key Points

Caveats

Further Discussion

 

Expected Benefit: Increased Economic Output

Naturally, the primary expected benefit of improved productivity is just increased economic output/higher GDP. Overall, if productivity could be boosted by just 1% per annum in the context of low-income countries, around 1.53 * 108 DALYs could potentially be gained, with this benefit modelled in the following way.

Moral Weights: I take the value of doubling consumption for one person for one year to be 0.21 DALYs. This is calculated as a function of (a) the value of consumption relative to life from GiveWell's IDinsight survey of the community perspective, as adjusted for social desirability bias, and (b) CEARCH's estimate of the value of a full, healthy life in DALY terms. For more details, refer to CEARCH's evaluative framework.

Scale: For this analysis, I normalize the degree of income increase per person to a 1% increase in productivity per annum (i.e. treating this as the baseline against which subsequent analysis of any productivity-increasing intervention is done). Correspondingly, this yields a 1% degree of consumption doubling per person. At the same time, the total number of people in low income countries in 2024 is around 739 million. Put together, the total number of consumption doublings achievable from raising productivity by 1% per annum for everyone in low income countries is 7.39 million.

Persistence: The potential economic gains from increased productivity are not something that are theoretically available only in a single year, but rather will accrue over many years. In terms of how this multi-year benefit is calculated:

Firstly, I discount for the probability of the solution not persisting. In this case, the solution is educational streaming (i.e. sorting students by ability and tailoring teaching to them accordingly); this is potentially one of the most impactful productivity-boosting interventions available, and this point this will be discussed at greater length later. For now, note that there is of course a year-on-year chance that such an educational policy is reversed. And to calculate the rate of policy reversal on educational streaming, I look at three case studies – Singapore, Malaysia and Finland.

In aggregating these reversal rates, equal weightage is used – yielding a reversal rate of around 0.6% per annum.

Secondly, I take into account the proportion of the potential benefit counterfactually remaining.

On the one hand, the potential benefit can diminish because productivity increases anyway due to educational gains that would have happened regardless (call this the per capita effect). Note that we can factor out all productivity gains from other sources, as that is not factored in as a potential benefit in the first place. As for modelling the productivity gains from educational advances that would have happened anyway (e.g. because of schools - whether government or private non-profit or private for-profit - improving pedagogy; or because of economic development bringing with it more resources that both state and private actors can spend on education) – we can roughly do this by modelling the average rate of convergence in harmonised learning outcome score (as calculated by Altinok, Angrist, and Patrinos), from the estimated 2024 global average score to the current top score, on the basis that this exhausts most of the gains available (given that diminishing marginal returns apply to productivity gains from education). From this, I estimate approximately a 0.4% per annum loss in counterfactual benefits to the fact that education is improving (and the world capturing the associated productivity gains) in any case.

On the other hand, the potential benefit can grow due to population growth increasing the number of people who can potentially benefit from having their consumption doubled (call this the population effect). For data, I pull from UN Population Division estimates up to 2100, and then assume constancy after. Diagram 1 shows global population over time, relative to the 2024 base.

Diagram 1: Global population, 2024-2100

Thirdly, I discount for the probability of the world being destroyed anyway (i.e. general existential risk discount) – around 0.07% per annum. This takes into account the probability of extinction, since the benefits of increased productivity to the people who would enjoy it would be nullified if said people would die in an extinction event anyway. For how this risk is calculated, refer to CEARCH's shallow research on nuclear war.

Fourthly, I apply a broad uncertainty discount of 0.1% per annum to take into account the fact that there is a non-zero chance that in the future, the benefits or costs do not persist for factors we do not and cannot identify in the present (e.g. actors directing resources to solve the problem when none are currently doing so).

Overall, by taking population growth, and discounting the number of potential beneficiaries each year by the various per annum discounts (i.e. solution reversal, existential risk, uncertainty), the total proportion of the benefit that is counterfactually achievable by a total solution relative to the 2024 baseline is shown in Diagram 2.

Diagram 2: Total proportion of productivity gains that is counterfactually achievable by a total solution

Finally, by summing the discounted per annum relative values for 2024-2100, and then using a perpetual value formula for 2101 to infinity, we see that the benefit of increased economic output will last for the equivalent of 98 baseline years.

Value of Outcome: Overall, the raw value of increased economic output is 1.53 * 108 DALYs, in the context of a 1% increase in productivity per annum in low-income countries.

Probability of Occurrence: There are two issues here – the probability of our chosen intervention working, and the probability that (even if the intervention succeeded in raising productivity), whether that increased productivity translates to increased income. The former issue – on intervention effectiveness – I leave to the final section of this report. On the latter – I raise this for conceptual completeness, but it's a fairly trivial issue, insofar as as claims on any goods or services produced will either be the owner's (i.e. his income), or else that of the capital owners and labourers he has to pay off (i.e. their income). Hence, the probability of productivity increasing income can be assigned ~1.

Expected Value: Hence, the expected value of increased economic output is 1.53 * 108 DALYs, in the context of a 1% increase in productivity per annum in low-income countries.

 

Expected Benefit: Improved Health from Increased Productivity

With economic improvement comes also the expected benefit of improved health. Overall, if productivity is boosted by 1% per annum in low-income countries, around 4.81 * 107 DALYs from health gains are potentially accruable, with this benefit modelled as follows.

Moral Weights: Here, what we're interested in is the DALYs averted per capita for each percentage point in growth of GDP per capita. To do this, I take the difference in DALYs lost per capita between high-income and low-income countries, and divide by the time needed for low-income countries to catch up to current high-income GDP per capita levels from current low-income GDP per capita levels at 1% growth per annum. DALYs lost per capita are age-standardized to factor out composition effects (i.e. richer countries happening to have older and less healthy citizens). In all, this method suggests that around 0.0007 DALYs per individual is gained from a 1% increase in productivity per annum in low income countries.

Scale: In term of potential beneficiaries, the total number of people in low income countries in the baseline year of 2024 is again 739 million.

Persistence: The same per annum discounts and the same projections of population growth over time, as discussed in the previous section, are used here as well, such the benefit of improved health from increased productivity will similarly last for the equivalent of 98 baseline years.

Value of Outcome: Overall, the raw perpetual value of improved health from increased productivity is 4.81 * 107 DALYs, in the context of a 1% increase in productivity per annum in low-income countries.

Probability of Occurrence: The probability of productivity improving health is a function of the probability of (a) productivity increasing income (~1, as discussed previously), and (b) the probability of increased income improving health. With respect to the latter, various studies – Baird et al, Filmer & Pritchett, Pritchett & Summers – point to the conclusion that increases in GDP per capita are associated with reductions in mortality in low- and middle-income countries. Hence, the idea that increased economic output leads to improved health (i.e. fewer deaths and less disability as well as pain) has a very high probability, and given the strong theoretical reasons for this (i.e. with increased economic output, countries can spend more on sanitation/nutrition/access to healthcare etc), this probability can be assigned ~1. And overall, therefore, the probability of productivity improving health outcomes can similarly be assigned ~1; there is no material uncertainty over this.

Expected Value: All in all, the expected value of improved health from increased productivity is 4.81 * 107 DALYs, in the context of a 1% increase in productivity per annum in low-income countries.


Tractability

The real question in all this, of course, is whether we can plausibly boost productivity above current trend – and if so, how much of a productivity boost we can achieve (e.g. will we gain less, equal or more than the nominal 1% baseline?)

To summarize our findings on tractability: we can capture 0.1% of above-mentioned income/health gains from a 1% productivity boost, via a USD 3.43 million investment into advocacy for educational streaming, which means the proportion of the problem solved per additional USD 100,000 spent is around 0.00003.


 

To begin with, let us discuss what intervention we should even be relying upon, to boost economic productivity:

 

Having settled on an intervention, we can now lay out our theory of change:


 

Step 1: To estimate the probability of successfully lobbying a government to implement streaming, I consult both the outside and inside view.

For the outside view, I consult three reference classes: the success rate of general lobbying attempts in (a) the US and (b) the EU; and on top of that, I look at the success rate of (c) nonprofit advocacy attempts in China. The US/EU cases are theoretically less representative insofar as lobbying in rich countries is harder than lobbying poor ones, but at the same time China is probably uniquely difficult to influence due to the closed political system. Ultimately, equal weightage is used, producing an aggregate outside view probability of 32%.

For the inside view, I reason as follows. Streaming/tracking seems fairly common, whether in East Asia (e.g. Singapore/China/Japan/South Korea) or Europe (e.g. Austria/Germany/Hungary/Slovakia) – hence, the idea will not seem especially radical to a policymaker, and correspondingly it doesn't seem at all improbable that a government is convinced by a nonprofit working on this to try out streaming (i.e. not <=10% chance of success). At the same time, advocacy is fundamentally hard, and it seems unlikely that this will have a >=50% chance of success. Given the context of working in low-income countries where governments defer more to NGOs than rich world governments do, I would tend to say that the average chance of success is on the moderately higher end of these stipulated bounds – perhaps 33% or so.

When aggregating the outside and inside views, it's important to note that it's unclear how lobbying success rates in rich world countries (or China, which is fairly sui generis in its political system) translates to low-income countries; on the other hand, there are the usual worries about inferential uncertainties for the inside view. Hence, equal weightage is used, which yields a combined probability of 32%.

 

Step 2: To estimate the probability of a persuaded government successfully implementing streaming, I once more consult both the outside and inside views.

For the outside view, I use as reference classes the same three countries examined in the context of policy reversal – Singapore, Malaysia, and Finland – and examine their execution of official streaming policy. Singapore, on its part, successfully streams secondary school students into express vs normal streams, as does Malaysia successfully stream its high school students into arts vs science streams. As for Finland – before it moved to a comprehensive system, it successfully streamed students into grammar schools vs public comprehensives. The upshot of all this is a 100% success rate (instances of success per attempt to stream) for each country and hence in aggregate (n.b. equal weightage is used, not that it matters).

For the inside view, I reason as follows. It's conceptually not difficult at all to test students by ability and then sort them into the relevant classes/schools to be taught to different extents/at different speeds. Hence, the chances of success do not appear very low (i.e. <=10%); indeed, it appears better than even (i.e. >50%). On the other hand, some of these low income countries are fairly wartorn/beset by political instability, and it's not out of the question that such countries are unable to carry out basic functions like administering national tests and the organization of schools into different educational streams - hence, I conservatively assume that there is a 66% chance of successfully carrying out streaming conditional on a low income government trying.

In combining the outside and inside views, I use equal weightage, producing an 83% success rate for streaming implementation – though inside views are typically beset by inferential uncertainties, the outside view is fairly unrepresentative (i.e. taking reference from high/medium income countries when the median intervention country will be Malawi at best and the Congo at worst).


Step 3: To estimate the extent to which streaming increases educational performance, in test score standard deviations, I use an empirical estimate – per Duflo, Dupas and Kremer's RCT in Kenya, streaming increases test performance by 0.182 SD in the short run and by 0.235 SD in the long run – I use an average of both (i.e. 0.209).

 

Step 4: Finally, to estimate the extent to which improved educational performance increases income and hence captures the available economic/health gains, I use another empirical estimate – per Hanushek and Kimko, a one SD increase in test scores translates to a 1.4% increase in GDP per capita growth. In modelling the aggregate effects, I make the simplifying assumption that this applies (eventually) to everyone in a single (low-income) intervention country who is educated to at least the secondary school level. Via this approach, we see that improved educational performance of one SD's worth of test scores in the likely student population captures around 2% of potential economic/health gains.

 

Overall, the proportion of income/health gains from productivity captured by educational streaming policy advocacy – as a function of (a) the probability of successfully lobbying a government to implement streaming; (b) the probability of a persuaded government successfully implementing streaming; (c) the extent to which streaming increases educational performance, in test score standard deviations; and (d) the extent to which improved educational performance increases income and hence captures the available economic/health gains – is ultimately 0.001.


Meanwhile, on the costing side, we have to be concerned with both the cost of advocacy (for a nonprofit working on the matter) and the cost of execution (for the government).

To estimate the cost of advocacy, I consider two reference classes – an existing charity and a hypothetical Charity Entrepreneurship-incubated charity.

For the former, I look at Pratham, which basically helps to carry out educational streaming via its programme of Teaching at the Right Level in India, though it is also scaling into Africa, the rest of South Asia and Latin America. Pratham is also a former GiveWell standout organization, albeit from more than a decade ago when standards were different/not as high. Here, I use its UK costing, converting GBP into USD. I assess that around 1 year of operations is a reasonable timeframe for the charity to do geographic selection, subsequent in-country preparatory activities (e.g. prepare supporting research reports on the economic and health benefits of the policy, conducting public polling to show public support, construct a coalition of NGOs and advocates, convince past and present politicians to be legislative champions) and to actually lobby the sitting government - and hence succeed (in which case it can pivot to a different country) or judge that policymakers are just not receptive and that its efforts have failed (in which case it can pivot or else shutdown). Overall, this yields a single-year cost of around USD 1,640,000.

For the hypothetical CE incubatee – the typical structure is that of 2 co-founders, with funding of around USD 50,000 per person per annum. I also make the assumption that the charity will mainly be engaged in advocacy, while relying on Pratham or government partners to do actual execution (of testing and teaching). And, as before, I take a year to be a reasonable timeframe for either identifiable success or failure. In all, this translates to a single-year cost of USD 100,000.

In averaging these two perspectives, we should note that  while the existing organization's financial track record generally gives a much better indication of baseline expenditure requirements in the cause area, Pratham's spending is not representative here given the different operating model; and in any case, the explicitly EA-aligned CE-incubatee will almost certainly be more cost-effective. Hence, I weigh towards the incubatee's costs, and find that the money required to conduct lobbying will probably be around USD 240,000

As for the cost of execution – to estimate the cost of ongoing national testing, I do the following things:

With all this done, the cost of actually executing streaming as an educational policy is probably around USD 3,190,000

Put together, the total cost of the intervention will be around USD 3,430,000.


Consequently, the proportion of the problem solved per additional USD 100,000 spent is around 0.00003.

 

Marginal Expected Value of Educational Streaming Advocacy to Boost Productivity

All in all, the marginal expected value of educational streaming advocacy to boost productivity is 5,582 DALYs per USD 100,000 spent, making this around 9x as cost-effective as a GiveWell top charity.


 


Arturo Macias @ 2023-01-25T09:04 (+4)

I have serious structural doubts about   educational emphasis.  Education and economic opportunity feed each other in such a way that it is hard to disentangle cause and effect. 

It is clear that education can be a produced at the individual leven when the rate of return of human capital is high enough. On the other hand, the social bottlenecks (cultural, political+ extractive elites...) to development are hard to remove.  

It is quite typical to interpret the income education correlation as causation from education to income. This is absolutely anti intuitive on my view. Do you know any literature adressing that concern?

Joel Tan (CEARCH) @ 2023-01-26T01:52 (+1)

The causality could well runs both ways, since plausibly education improves productivity and income, even as countries/people spend more on education as they get richer. To get around this problem of reverse causality, the Dieppe et al analysis we rely on basically regresses 1960-2018 growth rates on 1960 education levels and other candidate explanations like innovation or institutions (since obviously future growth rates cannot affect the past).

However, as I note in the report, this doesn't eliminate the problem completely, since possibly 1960-2018 growth rates are autocorrelated with pre-1960 growth rates, which then influence 1960 education levels etc.

That said, my conclusion is that this is sufficiently unlikely given the theoretical and empirical case against consistently positive autocorrelation between past and future productivity growth:

  • In theory, copying technological/educational/managerial innovations etc and catch-up growth is just easier than inventing further new ideas.
  • Empirically, advanced economies underperform the global average of productivity growth while developing economies over-perform.

And if we don't expect future growth rates to be positively correlated with past growth rates, then it wouldn't be growth boosting education (through higher growth allowing more spending on education). And hence, we can be fairly confident that reverse causality is probably not driving the results. I discuss this all in greater detail in the report.

Arturo Macias @ 2023-01-26T07:35 (+1)

"To get around this problem of reverse causality, the Dieppe et al analysis we rely on basically regresses 1960-2018 growth rates on 1960 education levels and other candidate explanations like innovation or institutions (since obviously future growth rates cannot affect the past)"

https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/34015

In page 124 they say: 

"Endogeneity. The Bayesian approach used in the chapter can help to overcome ad hoc variable selection and the arbitrary omission of variables. Issues of interpretation remain, because many candidate explanatory variablesβ€”innovation, democracy, rule of law, trade, education, health, investment, and so onβ€”are best seen as equilibrium outcomes. Because growth and the explanatory variables are jointly determined, it is hard to draw conclusions about causal effects, and persuasive instrumental variables are hard to find."

I have made this question many times before, and unfortunately your answer is among the best I have received (at least you are aware and have an estimate, while non-causal). 

Now, given that a hard answer is unavailable, I will state my impression: when you educate people beyond the absortion capabilities of an economy,  you end up producing social unstability and intensify elite overpopulation. So, I believe educational intervention works, but only as long as it is not generic education that feeds inter elite competitions, but it is targeted to economic needs.

Currently, for developing countries, intenet access and education focused on complementarity with the needs of developed contries (to ride the likely  wave of outsourcing) is probably the best option to create export opportunities, instead of frustrated graduates looking for a revolution. 

Joel Tan (CEARCH) @ 2023-01-27T01:29 (+1)

The elite overproduction hypothesis is always interesting (not sure of robustness even in the context of the US and other advanced economies where the case for it would be strongest), but probably not a worry in the context of low income countries where it's just primary/secondary education we're looking at.