"Should have been hired" Prizes
By Larks @ 2022-01-19T14:19 (+38)
Retrospective Employment Bounties
Funding socially beneficial work in retrospect is an idea that has been frequently discussed (e.g. here) but has had a variety of problems in practice, including the difficulty in concretely identifying ahead of time what will be in retrospect eligible.
A possible solution to this would be to exploit an existing area where such organisations already make such deliberations: hiring. At present orgs evaluate researchers, estimating their expected research contributions to that organisation’s agenda. If this estimate is high, the researcher is hired. If it is low, the researcher is rejected.
Sometimes these estimates are wrong, however, and sometimes the candidate might have good reason to believe this. Perhaps he knows he underperformed his true potential at the interview, or struggled to explain his ideas, or simply thinks the interviewers were mistaken about some crucial consideration. In these cases it might be good if the researcher was incentivised to work on the research anyway, as if he had been hired.
This could be achieved if the organisation credibly promised to pay rejected applicants in retrospect if their work turned out to be sufficiently good that they should have been hired. In order to account for risk, the organisation might offer a multiple of the salary + benefits they would have offered. For example, if the organisation thinks their marginal hire (that they actually hired) has a 50% chance of producing work of quality X, they should be willing to pay 2x compensation for any rejected candidate who nonetheless produces quality X work.
The organisation could additionally hire the researcher at this point, but this is not a necessary component. Additionally, this system could be combined into a broader Impact Certificates program - it would essentially be a commitment to purchase certificates at a certain price - but can stand on its own. Some mechanism may be required to ensure that multiple organisations do not fund the same work.
Advantages of this approach:
- Incentivise additional work
- The prospect of compensation (and vindication!) may induce additional research effort on useful topics.
- Guide research
- Independent researchers will have some sense of what to work on: instead of ‘produce valuable things’, they have the slightly more concrete ‘things this organisations thinks are valuable’.
- Pay for Performance
- Only research successes require payment.
- Existing Evaluation Criteria
- Organisations already make hiring decisions, so there is relatively little novel evaluative work required.
- Save overhead
- If rejected candidates can produce good work independently, you are relieved of the costs of managing them.
- Fail gracefully
- If no organisations adopt this policy, or no spurned applicants pursue it, little is lost.
Disadvantages of this approach:
- Waste Time
- Low quality, correctly rejected candidates might waste their time on a quixotic quest for vindication.
- Limited Scope
- This can only induce counterfactual effort from rejected candidates, a relatively small pool.
- If organisations are good at hiring, this may be a weak pool.
- Dissatisfaction
- Being rejected from such a prize could add insult to the injury of the initial rejection.
- Some people might disagree with the retrospective evaluation and feel cheated.
- Risk aversion / diminishing marginal utility
- A guarantee of Y dollars is more valuable than a 50% chance of 2*Y, so this produces less utility for researchers than if they had been hired (though this was not on the table as they were rejected).
- Duplication of effort
- Multiple researchers may require compensation for the same insights in a way that could be avoided if the organisation was directly allocating their labour.
- Financial planning
- Uncertainty about how many such prizes will be earned could make it harder for an organisation to predict their future expenditure. But I would expect that, if this is a good idea, donors could be found to underwrite the expense.
What next?
Having put this idea out there I have little intention of promoting it further, but would be happy to discuss or help any organisations that found it interesting.
Ozzie Gooen @ 2022-01-19T15:00 (+56)
This is an interesting idea, thanks for raising it!
I think intuitively, it worries me. As someone around hiring in these sorts of areas, I'm fairly nervous around the liabilities that come from hiring, and this seems like it could increase these. (Legal, and just upsetting people).
I'm imagining:
- There's a person who thinks they're great, but the hiring manager really doesn't see it. They get rejected.
- They decide to work on it anyway, saying they'll get the money later.
- They continue to email the org about their recent results, hoping to get feedback, sort of similar to as an employee.
- 6-20 months later, they have some work, and are sure that it deserves funding.
- The work isn't that great, and the prize is denied.
- They get really upset that their work has been denied.
This system could create "pseudo-employees" who are trying to act as employees, but aren't really employees. This just seems pretty messy.
In addition, funding seems tricky. Like, a lot of research nonprofits don't have that much extra funding allocated in their budgets for this. I imagine it would have to be coordinated with funders, on-demand. ("Hey, funder X... person Y, who we rejected, just did good work, and now we need $160k to fund them. Can you donate that money to us, so we can retrospectively pay them?")
I could also see the tax/legal implications as messy, though that could be resolved with time.
Generally, if someone seems pretty strong and capable of doing independent work, I suggest they apply to the LTFF, and say that I could help discuss their application. The LTFF funds a lot of people at this point. Small funders like the LTFF seem like great escape hatches for these situations. So this technique would really make sense, I assume, if both the LTFF rejects them, and I'm pretty confident they have a solid chance of doing good research. This is pretty unusual.
It's quite possible the benefits overcome these negatives. I'm not sure, I just wanted to share my quick feelings on this.
saulius @ 2022-01-19T14:59 (+16)
Oh wow, literally just minutes I independently made a similar suggestion in a shortform here. My idea is a bit different because I propose that people would apply to EA funds (or other funds) to do research and would be paid after their research is done, depending on how good/impactful their research was. I thought I should mention it here because pursuing any one of these two ideas would probably be enough.
quinn @ 2022-01-20T16:06 (+6)
I think you missed a disadvantage: I think there's a free rider problem where everyone reaps the benefits of the research and it's too easy for a given org to decline funding it.
Overall I like the idea a lot and
Some mechanism may be required to ensure that multiple organisations do not fund the same work.
I hope to find time for this exercise later today.
FCCC @ 2022-01-22T02:04 (+1)
One big change that a lot of employers can make is changing their interviews and written tests.
I’ve been required to create a new policy from scratch in interview settings. “Okay now you should come up with an idea on the spot, and you will need to say why this policy should now be a legal requirement of every person in the country.” It’s exactly that type of surface-level thinking that policymakers should avoid.
You should be allowed to bring in work that you’ve already made into the interview and for the written application. It’s far more reflective of the work you will do, because it is the work that you’ve done. Plans for future policy writings mean nothing because there very well could be some technical reason why your nascent policy idea is fundamentally flawed.