Report on Social Returns to Productivity Growth
By Tom_Davidson @ 2022-07-15T22:31 (+55)
This is a linkpost to https://www.openphilanthropy.org/research/report-on-social-returns-to-productivity-growth/
Historically, economic growth has had huge social benefits, lifting billions out of poverty and improving health outcomes around the world. This leads some to argue that accelerating economic growth, or at least productivity growth,[1] should be a major philanthropic and social priority going forward.[2]
I’ve written a report in which I evaluate this view in order to inform Open Philanthropy’s Global Health and Wellbeing (GHW) grantmaking. Specifically, I use a relatively simple model to estimate the social returns to directly funding research and development (R&D). I focus on R&D spending because it seems like a particularly promising way to accelerate productivity growth, but I think broadly similar conclusions would apply to other innovative activities.
My estimate, which draws heavily on the methodology of Jones and Summers (2020), asks two primary questions:
- How much would a little bit of extra R&D today increase people’s incomes into the future, holding fixed the amount of R&D conducted at later times?[3]
- How much welfare is produced by this increase in income?
In brief, I find that:
- The social returns to marginal R&D are high, but typically not as high as the returns in other areas we’re interested in. Measured in our units of impact (where “1x” is giving cash to someone earning $50k/year) I estimate that the cost-effectiveness of funding R&D is 45x. This is ~4% as impactful as the (roughly 1,000x) GHW bar for funding.
- Put another way, I estimate that $20 billion to “average” R&D has the same welfare benefit as increasing the incomes of 180 million people by 10% each for one year.
- That said, the best R&D projects might have much higher returns. So could projects aimed at increasing the amount of R&D (for example, improving science policy).
- This estimate is very rough, and I could readily imagine it being off by a factor of 2-3 in either direction, even before accounting for the limitations below.
- Returns to R&D were plausibly much higher in the past. This is because R&D was much more neglected, and because of feedback loops where R&D increased the amount of R&D occurring at later times.
- My estimate has many important limitations. For example, it omits potential downsides to R&D (e.g. increasing global catastrophic risks), and it focuses on a specific scenario in which historical rates of return to R&D continue to apply even as population growth stagnates.
- Alternative scenarios might change the bottom line. For instance, R&D today might speed up the development of some future technology that drastically accelerates R&D progress. This would significantly increase the returns to R&D, but in my view would also strengthen the case for Open Phil to focus on reducing risks from that technology rather than accelerating its development.
Overall, the model implies that the best R&D-related projects might be above our GHW bar, but it also leaves us relatively skeptical of arguments that accelerating innovation should be the primary social priority going forward.
In the full report, I also discuss:
- How alternative scenarios might affect social returns to R&D.
- What these returns might have looked like in the year 1800.
- How my estimates compare to those of economics papers that use statistical techniques to estimate returns to R&D growth.
- The ways in which my current views differ from those of certain thinkers in the Progress Studies movement.
- ^
If environmental constraints require that we reduce our use of various natural resources, productivity growth can allow us to maintain our standards of living while using fewer of these scarce inputs.
- ^
For example: in Stubborn Attachments, Tyler Cowen argues that the best way to improve the long-run future is to maximize the rate of sustainable economic growth. A similar view is held by many of those involved in the Progress Studies community.
- ^
An example of an intervention causing a temporary boost in R&D activity would be to fund some researchers for a limited period of time. Another example would be to bring forward in time a policy change that permanently increases the number of researchers.
Henry Howard @ 2022-07-16T00:37 (+2)
One problem with averaging all R&D in the world is that some of it might be much more effective at improving economic growth than other research. I don't know where you get the $2 trillion global annual research spend value but I wonder how much of this is things like:
- focus group research on whether people prefer breakfast cereal A to B
- market research on which social media algorithm is best for marketing product X
- research on producing better tank armour, then research on how to produce missiles to pierce that armour and make it redundant and so on.
It seems like a more targeted approach to R&D specifically aiming at improving economic growth could be magnitudes more effective than "average" R&D
Lorenzo @ 2022-07-17T21:46 (+2)
This is actually mentioned in the report: https://www.openphilanthropy.org/research/social-returns-to-productivity-growth/#the_best_pro_growth
A second caveat is that we’ve estimated the average impact of marginal R&D funding. Of course, the actual impact of any particular grant could be much larger or much smaller than this, depending on the project being funded. If a funder can consistently identify particularly promising projects, their impact could be larger than my estimate. One way to do this might be to focus on R&D projects that are specifically designed to help the global poor. Just as $1 goes further when transferred to the global poor, so too R&D might be more effective when targeted in this way.
Some of those involved with Progress Studies think accelerating innovation should be the world’s top priority. I discuss ways in which my outlook differs from theirs in this appendix.
And in the appendix:
I expect, partly based on unpublished work by Open Philanthropy, that some such opportunities do meet the GHW bar. In other words, I think that some interventions to boost innovation are among the best in the world for improving wellbeing.
Tom_Davidson @ 2022-08-23T16:27 (+1)
Sorry for the slow reply!
I agree you can probably beat this average by aiming specifically at R&D for boosting economic growth.
I'd be surprised if you could spend $100s millions per year and consistently beat the average by a large amount (>5X) though:
- The $2 trillion number also excludes plenty of TFP-increasing research work done by firms that don't report R&D like Walmart and many services firms.
- The broad areas where this feels most plausible to me (R&D in computing or fundamental bio-tech) are also the areas that have the biggest potential downsides risks.
- To have impact you need to fund projects that wouldn't otherwise receive funding
- Governments and other funders want to fund things that increase growth. I'm sceptical you can be (e.g.) 10X as good as these funders at identifying bets ex ante.
Another relevant point is that some interventions increase R&D inputs in a non-targeted, or weakly targeted, way. E.g. high-skill immigration to the US or increasing government funding for broad R&D pots. The 'average R&D' number seems particularly useful for these interventions.
Anthony Repetto @ 2022-08-04T03:53 (+1)
Apologies for forming a separate thread - I was just informed that the author posted here, as well.
Here is the link, if you are curious: https://forum.effectivealtruism.org/posts/xEyzE2DGSiMQGjqmz/a-response-to-openphil-s-r-and-d-model
Tom_Davidson @ 2022-08-23T16:34 (+1)
Thanks for this!
I won't address all of your points right now, but I will say that I hadn't considered that "R&D is compensating for natural resources becoming harder to extract over time", which would increase the returns somewhat. However, my sense is that raw resource extraction is a small % of GDP, so I don't think this effect would be large.